Coordinating supplier-retailer using multiple common replenishment epochs with retailers’ choices


Coordinating supplier-retailer using multiple common replenishment epochs with retailers’ choices

Juhwen Hwang, Su-Hwa Wu

National Dong Hwa University (Taiwan, R.O.C.)



Received: September 2012

Accepted: January 2013





Hwang, J., & Wu, S-H. (2013). Coordinating supplier-retailer using multiple common replenishment epochs with retailers’ choices. Journal of Industrial Engineering and Management, 6(2), 441-455. http://dx.doi.org/10.3926/jiem.536



---------------------


Abstract:

Purpose: Provide a coordination strategy using multiple common replenishment epochs (MCRE) for a single-supplier multi-retailer supply chain.

Design/methodology/approach: The demand of a product occurs only with a group of heterogeneous and independent retailers with constant rates, whereas all their order requests are fulfilled by the supplier. The supplier decides a set of MCREs with general price and extra bonus to entice the retailers to join any one of the MCREs, or to let them remain with their original order time epochs. A retailer is willing to participate in a CRE as long as the retailer’s cost increase is within its tolerance. This paper provides a mixed integer programming to determine the MCRE strategies in order to minimize the total costs of the supplier.

Findings: The results illustrate that MCRE model provided in the paper can generate a better replenishment coordination scheme than single CRE models.

Practical implications: Replenishment coordination is one of the most important mechanisms to improve the efficiency in supply chains, e.g., chain convenience stores in the modern retail industry.

Originality/value: This is a follow-up research on Joint Economic Lot Size (JELS) models with a focus on multiple retailers with their replenishment coordination.

Keywords: supply chain, inventory management, common replenishment epoch

---------------------

1. Introduction

To obtain competitive advantages, supply chain partners often seek coordination to improve performance of the supply chain. As one of the most important supply chains in the modern retail industry, chain convenience stores have devoted significant efforts to improve supply coordination. As of 2012, the three famous convenience store chains, 7-Eleven, FamilyMart, and Couche-Tard, operate around 43,000, 17,560 and 6,000 convenience stores worldwide respectively (7-Eleven, 2012; FamilyMart, 2012; Alimentation Couche-Tard, 2012). The huge and continuously growing number of stores in chain convenience stores creates a persistent drive to improve their supply coordination. Often, a better coordination in the supply chain supports the products with an enhanced competitive advantage. In practice, the retailing industry with multiple stores would divide the distribution channels into various modules based on geographic areas, replenishment epochs, or some other managerial considerations to enhance logistic efficiency.

This paper studies a single-supplier, multiple-retailer supply chain for a single commodity. The demand of the commodity occurs only at the retailers with constant rates, and the supplier is responsible for replenishing all the retailers’ requests to satisfy their demands. The supplier is the leader of the supply chain, and it provides a sequence of prescheduled epochs for all the retailers to choose their order replenishment timings. The cost disadvantages of the retailers for joining the replenishment timings shall be compensated by the supplier through quantity discounts. In addition, the costs considered in the supply chain include setup and delivery costs of the supplier, as well as holding and ordering setup costs of the retailers. The objective of the supply chain is to minimize the total cost of the supplier.

2. Literature review

The importance of coordination in the supply chain is evidenced by the ample growth in the coordination literature. Fugate, Sahin, and Mentzer (2006) summarize the benefits of coordination including cost reduction, risk reduction, profit increase and competitive advantages enhancement. Interested readers can refer to Goyal and Gupta (1989), Sarmah Acharya and Goyal (2006, 2008), Arshinder, Kandaa and Deshmukh (2008), Chan and Chan (2010), and Chan (2011) for the review of the buyer-vendor coordination models.

Replenishment timing is one of the essential issues in inventory management. Heterogeneous retailers pursuing their own optimizations may order at various times. Nevertheless, the variations on retailers’ replenishment timings significantly increase the cost of the supplier for handling these replenishment orders. If replenishment orders can be synchronized, the relevant inventory costs can be reduced. Hence, replenishment coordination is one of the areas that research focuses on supply chain coordination, e.g., Yao and Chiou (2004), Chen and Chen (2005), Wu and Hwang (2011). In order to provide incentives for coordination, mechanisms such as quantity discount, buy-back/return policies, and quantity flexibility are often used (Tsay, Nahmias & Agrawal, 1999; Sarmah et al., 2006). However, quantity discount is considered to be one of the most popular coordination mechanisms (Weng, 1995; Jorgensen and Zaccour, 2003; Sarmah et al., 2006; Li & Wang, 2007).

Assume the supplier has all the relevant information about the retailer’s replenishment information, Viswanathan and Piplani (2001) first propose a CRE (Common Replenishment Epoch) coordination model wherein the supplier offers a price discount as the compensation and incentive for all buyers to participate in the coordination scheme. Under a CRE scheme, all participating retailers release requests only at the supplier’s required CREs. Their model is modified by Mishra (2004) with a selective discount policy in which some buyers are excluded under the chosen CRE and discount. Mishra solves a two CRE problem with an algorithm by segmenting buyers based on selective price discounts prior to assigning buyers into CREs. Piplani and Viswanathan (2004) focus on saving joint order processing costs for the orders placed by either one or both CREs at the same time. Feng and Viswanathan (2007) further reveal the effectiveness of coordinating supplier and retailers through a single CRE facing uncertain demand. Yao and Chiou (2009) propose a cooperative model with a saving-sharing mechanism to further enhance the performance of the supply chain within a single CRE consideration.

Note that Viswanathan and Piplani discuss a single CRE model, and Mishra studies a selective discount model with a single CRE or two CREs. The work of Piplani and Viswanathan assumes a dependent relationship between two CREs which seems restrictive in a practical sense. Our paper adopts the framework of Viswanathan and Piplani (2001) and Mishra (2004) and extends the model into a multiple CRE (MCRE) setting in which the multiple CREs are not dependent. The implementation of a multiple CRE (MCRE) schemes of the supplier in this paper is based on the frameworks of Viswanathan and Piplani (2001) and Mishra (2004). Nevertheless, our research develops a general discount (GD) model such that the choice of MCRE to the retailers is simply based on the criterion of minimizing the supplier’s total cost without pre-segmenting buyers into either one of MCREs or none.

3. Model formulation and analysis

Now, we are in a position to analyze a single-supplier multi-retailer replenishment problem for a retailing supply chain. In this section, we will first describe and analyze the problem of this paper. In the subsequent subsections, the problem will be formulated into two MCRE models, General Discount (GD) and Exact General Discount (EGD) MCRE. We name Mishra’s model as a Selective Discount (SD) model. GD is defined as a more general model than SD model. The SD will finally select a discount of a CRE based on the cost disadvantage of a retailer, and then any retailers have to join the CRE if and only if the following condition is true: a retailer’s disadvantage of joining the CRE is able to compensate through the discount selected. This condition is relaxed in the GD model such that every retailer is free to join a CRE as long as the minimum total cost of the supplier can be reached. The second MCRE model defined in this paper, EGD, is designed to remove redundancy of the joint order processing cost in the GD model, cf. Piplani and Viswanathan (2004), with a broader definition.

3.1. Model description

Consider a supply chain in which a supplier sells a product with a unit price P to m heterogeneous and self-governing retailers, where retailer i = 1,…,m has constant demand rate λi, holding cost rate hi, and order setup cost Ki. In the system, the supplier is the leader and considers an MCRE scheme with all the preferable CREs in a set X. The MCRE scheme is restricted to offer only w CREs from X for all the retailers to join. Thus, Xw is defined as a subset of X with w elements numbered as CRE j = 1,…,w. Each CRE j can be specified by the time interval between two consecutive ordering occasions τj, i.e., Xw = {τ1,…,τw}.

As long as a retailer participates in a CRE j scheme, the supplier offers incentives, including a selling price discount dj to compensate the retailer’s inventory cost increase, plus a bonus 100Sj measured as a fraction of the retailer’s original inventory cost. The price discount and the bonus only pertain to the retailers selecting the CRE, regardless of any particular retailer to avoid price discrimination. The incentives offered by the supplier represent how much it is willing to pay in order to achieve a better operational efficiency. At certain point of time, the supplier processes an order from a retailer i and incurs an order processing cost of Ui if the retailer i does not participate in any CRE. Conversely, the supplier incurs a joint order processing cost of AS for the entire MCRE orders with an additional cost of Aj dedicated for all the orders of a CRE j. In addition, the supplier incurs a delivery cost of Di for every order placed by the retailer i. Under the MCRE scheme, a retailer is willing to select one of the MCREs only if its inventory cost increase is below its limit of tolerance; otherwise, the retailer will choose to stick with its original time epoch. The magnitudes of cost increase indicate the retailer’s needs to adjust the changes. If the cost increases beyond the tolerance limit, some of the managerial impact may not be easily adjusted, e.g., limitations on storage and facilities, financial issues, human resources, and the product perishability, etc. Therefore, the retailer will simply reject the CRE offer. This is the rationale to incorporate retailers’ tolerance limits in the model. The limit of tolerance of a retailer i is denoted as a threshold ßi > 1, which is defined as the ratio of its inventory cost after and before participating. The threshold signifies the internal cost increase tolerance of the retailer, and is a criterion for the retailer to judge the supplier’s MCRE offer. Once the retailer i participates in the CRE j, its order interval must follow nijτj, where nij is a positive integer. In case that the retailer i selects its own order interval rather than any CRE, a dummy CRE w+1 is denoted as the choice of the retailer not to join the entire CREs in Xw. Thus, the decision of replenishment for a retailer considers its internal inventory cost increase as well as external CRE incentives from the supplier. The external incentives offered to the retailers by the supplier will be offset by the savings of the supplier’s internal cost through the participations of the retailers in the MCRE. The supplier’s savings results from tradeoffs between internal order processing costs for the retailers’ joint orders through the MCRE and the retailers’ original individual orders.

3.2. Model analysis

Before enacting an MCRE scheme, the optimal order interval of a retailer i is ti = with the inventory cost gi = and the total cost Ti = Pλi+gi. The supplier’s cost includes an order and a delivery costs for each retailer, and then the total cost is given by . When an MCRE scheme is enacted, a retailer i selecting a CRE j will set its replenishment interval tij = nijτj to minimize its inventory cost under the CRE. Hence, the inventory cost of the retailer i resulting from participating in the CRE j is gij = gi(ti/tij+tij/ti)/2 with the total cost Tij = (1dj)Pλi+gij. The optimal nij, denoted as nij*, such that gij(nij*) is minimized can be solved by using the inequality Then, we have nij*= [] where [x] is the largest integer not larger than x. Nevertheless, if gij/gi > ßi, the CRE is not eligible to the retailer due to the cost increase beyond its internal tolerance. Conversely, if a retailer i agrees with a CRE j, the supplier will offer a price discount and an extra savings to satisfy the inequality djλiP+(1Sj)gi > gij. The least discount offered by a CRE j acceptable to a retailer i is given by ρij = {gij(1Sj)gi}/λiP; this representation is similar to the one in Mishra (2004).

To avoid pre-segmenting retailers into any CRE, cf. Mishra’s SD model, two very useful indicators are introduced to conduct the following analysis toward our model. First, let γij belonging in {0,1} be the binary participation indicator for a retailer i to select a CRE j; γij = 1 indicates that the selection is true, γij = 0, otherwise. Note that the retailer i must choose a CRE from Xw or hold its own order interval; that is, the sum of decision variables γij over all j complies with . The second indicator is the feasibility indicator αij = [gi/gij1/ßi] for all i, j, where éxù is the smallest integer not smaller than x; αij = 1 indicates that retailer i is eligible to select a CRE j, i.e., gij/gi < ßi, αij = 0, otherwise. Notice that αi,w+1 = 1 for all i since any retailer is always feasible to hold its own order interval, i.e., gi,w+1gi. In addition, these two indicators jointly satisfy an equality for all the retailers.

3.3. General discount (GD) MCRE model

Now we are ready to define the first MCRE model in this paper, the GD MCRE Model. In GD model, every retailer is free to join a CRE as long as the minimum total cost of the supplier can be reached. The problem of the general discount (GD) MCRE model is to determine which member of Xw with corresponding τj, dj utilized by all the retailers to minimize the supplier’s total cost and can be formulated as follows:

Minimize ,

(1)

subject to , ,

(2)

, , ,

(3)

, ,

(4)

(5)

By utilizing (1), once the supplier decides which CREs are applied in Xw, the problem is simply to determine the optimal MCRE scheme i.e., to decide the values of dj and γij. The term [ ] in (1) is to detect whether or not a CRE j is utilized by any retailers. Employing the participation indicators allows us to process all the w CREs simultaneously. The constraints (2)~(5) allow GD to achieve minimum total cost in (1) for all the retailers with their best choice of price discount under all the available CREs. Therefore, GD Model shall make a cost improvement over the SD model in Mishra (2004).

Piplani and Viswanathan (2004) state that the models of Viswanathan and Piplani (2001) and Mishra (2004) may overestimate the order processing cost per unit time of the supplier as more than one CRE order occurs at the same time. By assuming a linear relationship of two CREs, Piplani and Viswanathan offer a procedure with three factors to remove the problem of order processing cost redundancy in the numerical examples. However, the redundancy of order processing costs G0 in (1) may hide the true optimal combination of the MCRE and discounts from the optimal solutions.

3.4. Exact general discount (EGD) MCRE model

In modern retailing industry, a supplier often utilizes a distribution center to process retailers’ order, the cost including order-picking and consolidation processes should be considered as a whole as long as the processes occur within a certain time frame. As a consequence, the supplier's relevant order processing costs may occur cost redundancy in GD model. The second MCRE model defined in the study, EGD, is designed to remove redundancy of the joint order processing cost in the GD model with a broader definition, and shall outperform the other models to reach a better coordination. To alleviate the order processing cost redundancy of G0 in (1), first of all, we develop an exact formula to calculate the numbers of orders or of CRE processed simultaneously at certain points of time. Thus, we are able to conclude how many orders and CRE are processed during a certain period of time.

In a practical sense, each CRE can be represented by a rational number with a scale measured in days, weeks, months, years, etc.; that is, all the elements in X are rational numbers. Based on the characteristics of rational numbers, there exists a largest real number V for the set Xw such that the ratio τj/V equals a positive integer lj for all j. All the orders released by a retailer i selecting a CRE j will be placed at time interval nijτj, i.e., nijljV, in which V can be interpreted as a unit length of all the CREs in Xw. Define an integer L as the least common multiplier of nijlj for all i, j, and then the time epoch LV is able to cover all possible retailers’ orders based on any CRE in Xw for at least one complete cycle. Furthermore, all the orders from the retailers joining any CRE in Xw will be released at time kV, where k = 1,…, L. Observe that while the retailer i is eligible to place an order at time kV, some of the time kV can be reached by nijτj times a positive integer such that the value of zijk = [k/nijlj] –[k/nijlj] either turns to 1, or turns to zero. By considering with the participation indicator, γijzijk = 1 if and only if the retailer i selects a CRE j and places an order at time kV; otherwise, γijzijk = 0. Let Zjk = , which can be interpreted as the number of orders released at time kV by all the retailers who select a CRE j. Further, define Yjk = [Zjk/m] ; Yjk = 1 be a sign of at least one order released at time kV by all the retailers who join a CRE j, and Yjk = 0, otherwise.

The roles of Yjk can be described by the following two dimensions. The first dimension is the summation of Yjk over the CRE j, , which represents how many CREs in Xw having at least one retailers’ order at time kV. Hence, [] = 1 indicates that there is at least one CRE having orders at time kV, and [] = 0, otherwise. Thus, define to represent the portion of kV, where k = 1,…,L, having at least one order from the retailers joining any CRE in Xw. As a result, for the time epoch LV, there are Lφ points of time having CRE orders with an order processing cost AS occurring at each time point. Hence, the total order processing cost for CRE orders during time epoch LV is LφAS, and the total order processing cost per unit time is φAS /V.

The second dimension describing the roles of Yjk is the summation of Yjk over the number k, , which represents how many points of time within time LV having orders based on the CRE j. Thus, define to represent the portion of kV, where k = 1,…,L, having at least one order from the retailers joining the CRE j. As a result, for the time LV, there are Lφj points of time having orders from the CRE j with an order processing cost Aj occurring at each time point. Hence, the total order processing cost for CRE orders in Xw during time LV is LφjAj, and the total order processing cost per unit time is φjAj/V for all j.

The supplier’s total cost with savings of the overestimated order processing costs in (1) can be revised as follows:

(6)

Equation (6) is the total cost function of the Exact General Discount (EGD) MCRE model. The definition of Yjk, having orders through a particular CRE at a certain point of time, is to formulate φj and φ as the portion of ordering occasions having orders through a particular CRE and through any CRE in Xw, respectively. The explicit expressions of φj and φ in our model are in contrast to Piplani and Viswanathan (2004). They use three factors to reach the same effect of φ but with numerical expressions by examples, and do not consider an ordering processing cost, such as Aj, for an individual order within a CRE. Consequently, by substituting (6) into (1), the EGD Model is definitely an improvement over the GD Model.

4. Numerical examples

Based on the development of our GD and EGD models, all the retailers have more freedom to choose from a set of replenishment epochs than the SD model as long as the minimum total cost of the supplier can be reached. Moreover, the cost redundancy for order processing is removed in EGD model to match up with the modern logistics operations in the retailing industry. The numerical examples developed in this section are to show the advantages of our GD and EGD models over Mishra’s SD model. In addition, some managerial insights will also be drawn from the numerical examples. Thus, we employ the numerical examples used in Mishra (2004) with an identical set of fifteen retailers and various processing costs of the supplier. The numerical examples can be referred to how a set of retailers efficiently participating various subsets of distribution channels provided by the supplier with a set of replenishment epochs. The methodologies for the retailers to decide their own subsets are restricted by SD, GD, and EGD models. The demands with the costs of order setup and holding of fifteen retailers are shown in Table 1. The value ranges of processing costs of the supplier are Aj = 0, for all j, Ui =10, 100, 200, 500, 1000 and Di = 10, 100, 200, 500, 1000, for all i, and AS = Ui or 3Ui. The supplier’s preferable CRE set is X (in weeks) = {1/7,3/7,1,2,3,4,5,6,7,8,9,10,10,11,12,13}. The saving percentage Sj is assumed to be 10% for any CRE. In Section 4.1, the numerical results of GD and Mishra’s SD in a single CRE fashion will be shown. The numerical results between EGD and SD in a multiple CRE fashion will be compared in Section 4.2.

Retailer

1

2

3

4

5

6

7

8

9

10

11

12

13

14

15

Ki

50

50

150

50

150

100

500

500

1500

500

1500

1000

5000

3000

3000

λi (in mill.)

2

1

2

0.5

1

0.5

2

1

2

0.5

1

0.5

2

1

0.5

hi

0.15

Table 1. Data for retailers

4.1. CRE under general discount (GD) vs. selective discount (SD)

This subsection describes single CRE models, in which the supplier offers a set of time epochs to all the retailers, and the retailers can only pick up a single time epoch. The objective of models is to minimize the supplier's relevant cost. We term our GD model using (1) with βi = 2 for all i as GD0, and GD0 without retailers’ choices as GD0N, i.e., 1/βi = 0, for all i. We first obtain the single CRE results of GD0N and GD0, and then compare with the results of Mishra’s SD model in Table 2. The first columns of SD, GD0N and GD0 in Table 2 indicate the savings (denoted as S% and D% denotes discount all through the paper) over the situation with no coordination. The second columns show the resulting CRE policies. The third column of GD0N demonstrates the savings by excluding the retailers with retailers’ choice, and the number of retailers excluded from the results of the second column. Table 2 shows that the savings of GD0N are better than those of SD in 31 out of 50 examples, and the savings are the same for the remaining 19 examples. When considering the retailers’ tolerance, 22 out 50 examples have at least one retailer over its tolerance with GD0N, e.g., there are two retailers over their individual tolerances in Ex30. By excluding those retailers out of these examples, the savings drop a little bit, e.g., the savings of Ex30 decline from 36.4% to 28.3%. Now, by using model GD0, we are able to increase the savings for all 22 examples, and 12 out of 22 examples even have better savings than SD, e.g., the savings of Ex30 with GD0 is 28.3%, where that of SD is only 25.1%.

The numerical results in this subsection show that by relaxing pre-segmentation of the retailers in the SD model, GD0N offers more flexibility to each retailer to select a better CRE. On the other hand, it is reasonable to see that GD0 may have less cost savings of the supplier than GD0N since GD0 offers retailers’ considerations in their cost disadvantages. GD0 shall be considered as a different model from GD0N; actually, GD0 incorporates the magnitude of the cost disadvantage of the retailer joining a CRE.





SD

GD0N

GD0

Ex

AS

Ui

Di

S(%)

CRE-D(%)-

# Included

S(%)

CRE-D(%)- # Included

S(%)-# excluded from previous column

S(%)

CRE-D(%)-

# Included

1

10

10

10

0.0

--

0.0

--

--

--

--

2

100

0.8

2-0.07-3

5.5

2-0.11-2

--

--

--

3

200

6.2

2-0.11-5

12.0

3-0.23-3

--

--

--

4

500

15.4

3-0.23-10

25.1

4-0.36-6

17.3-1

22.4

3-0.23-6

5

1000

25.2

3-0.23-10

36.4

6-0.64-6

17.2-2

28.4

3-0.23-7

6

100

100

10

31.7

2-0.11-6

31.7

2-0.11-6

--

--

--

7

100

23.8

2-0.11-6

23.8

2-0.11-6

--

--

--

8

200

20.9

2-0.11-5

24.3

3-0.23-6

--

--

--

9

500

25.6

3-0.23-10

31.5

4-0.36-7

22.1-1

29.3

3-0.23-7

10

1000

30.0

3-0.23-10

39.1

6-0.64-6

18.6-2

31.8

3-0.23-7

11

200

200

10

48.6

2-0.12-8

48.6

2-0.12-8

--

--

--

12

100

38.7

2-0.12-8

38.7

2-0.12-8

--

--

--

13

200

32.9

2-0.12-8

36.0

3-0.23-9

--

--

--

14

500

33.9

3-0.23-10

37.1

4-0.36-7

26.1-1

35.5

3-0.23-8

15

1000

34.4

3-0.23-10

41.6

6-0.64-6

21.0-2

35.2

3-0.23-8

16

500

500

10

63.3

2-0.17-10

63.3

2-0.17-10

--

--

--

17

100

57.7

3-0.23-10

57.7

3-0.23-10

--

--

--

18

200

54.5

3-0.23-10

54.5

3-0.23-10

--

--

--

19

500

48.9

3-0.26-12

49.6

4-0.36-11

37.0-1

48.9

3-0.26-12

20

1000

45.4

4-0.36-14

49.6

6-0.64-10

26.7-2

44.5

3-0.26-12

21

1000

1000

10

74.7

3-0.26-12

74.7

3-0.26-12

--

--

--

22

100

71.5

3-0.26-12

71.5

3-0.26-12

--

--

--

23

200

68.6

3-0.26-12

68.6

3-0.26-12

--

--

--

24

500

62.0

3-0.26-12

62.6

4-0.36-12

46.7-1

62.0

3-0.26-12

25

1000

58.0

5-0.50-15

59.0

5-0.50-12

43.9-1

55.5

3-0.26-12

26

30

10

10

0.0

--

0.0

--

--

--

--

27

100

0.0

--

3.7

2-0.11-2

--

--

--

28

200

5.3

2-0.11-5

11.4

3-0.23-3

--

--

--

29

500

15.1

3-0.23-10

24.9

4-0.36-6

17.1-1

22.2

3-0.23-6

30

1000

25.1

3-0.23-10

36.4

6-0.64-6

17.14-2

28.3

3-0.23-7

31

300

100

10

14.2

2-0.11-6

14.2

2-0.11-6

--

--

--

32

100

14.2

2-0.11-6

14.2

2-0.11-6

--

--

--

33

200

14.5

2-0.11-5

20.0

3-0.23-6

--

--

--

34

500

23.4

3-0.23-10

29.9

4-0.36-7

20.45-1

27.2

3-0.23-7

35

1000

28.8

3-0.23-10

38.5

6-0.64-6

18.00-2

30.6

3-0.23-7

36

600

200

10

30.2

2-0.12-8

30.2

2-0.12-8

--

--

--

37

100

25.8

2-0.12-8

27.8

3-0.23-8

--

--

--

38

200

26.4

3-0.23-10

29.6

3-0.23-8

--

--

--

39

500

30.2

3-0.23-10

34.3

4-0.36-7

23.31-1

31.8

3-0.23-8

40

1000

32.3

3-0.23-10

40.5

6-0.64-6

18.81-2

33.0

3-0.23-8

41

1500

500

10

49.1

3-0.23-10

49.1

3-0.23-10

--

--

--

42

100

47.0

3-0.23-10

47.0

3-0.23-10

--

--

--

43

200

45.3

3-0.23-10

45.3

3-0.23-10

--

--

--

44

500

42.4

3-0.26-12

44.8

4-0.36-11

32.19-1

42.4

3-0.26-12

45

1000

42.8

5-0.50-15

47.5

6-0.64-10

24.56-2

40.3

3-0.26-12

46

3000

1000

10

62.0

3-0.26-12

62.0

3-0.26-12

--

--

--

47

100

59.9

3-0.26-12

60.4

4-0.36-13

44.39-1

59.9

3-0.26-12

48

200

58.5

4-0.36-14

59.1

4-0.36-13

43.11-1

57.9

3-0.26-12

49

500

55.6

4-0.36-14

56.2

4-0.36-13

40.27-1

53.5

3-0.26-12

50

1000

54.2

5-0.50-15

55.5

6-0.64-11

29.65-2

49.1

3-0.26-12

Table 2. Numerical examples with single CRE

4.2. MCRE under general discount vs. exact general discount

The supplier offers a set of time epochs to all the retailers as described in subsection 4.1. Similar to the condition that the supplier offers a set of time epochs to all the retailers, in this subsection, however, any retailer can pick up a time epoch for her own as long as the supplier's relevant cost is minimized. Considering the MCRE scheme, we present numerical examples for a two-CRE problem. The result of seven examples with Ex 3, 8, 13, and 16~19 are compared as displayed in Table 3. Results in Table 3 show that GD0N has better savings than SD in 4 out of 7 examples and equal values for the rest of 3 examples. Moreover, by removing the redundancy in processing costs from GD0N, consider (6) without retailers’ choices as EGDRN. EGDRN has better savings than GD0N and SD in all 7 examples. EGDRN, GD0N and SD have impacts not only on the savings but also on the resulting CRE policies. Table 3 also indicates the values of V, L, φ, φ1, and φ2 of the corresponding CREs in the second column of EGDRN. The processing cost factor φ for entire CRE orders plays an important role of further savings; in contrast, the processing cost factors φ1, and φ2 for each CRE orders do not affect the savings since we assume A1 = A2 = 0 in all the examples.



SD

GD0N

EGDRN

Ex

S (%)

CRE - D(%)-

# Included

S (%)

CRE - D(%)- # Included

S (%)

CRE - D(%)-

# Included

φ

φ1

φ2

V

L

3

6.2

2-0.11-5; 3-0.08-1

14.3

2-0.11-1; 3-0.17-2

14.6

2-0.11-2; 4-0.21-2

1.00

1.00

0.50

2

840

8

21.8

2-0.11-6; 4-0.14-3

26.4

2-0.11-3; 4-0.21-3

28.0

2-0.11-3; 4-0.21-3

1.00

1.00

0.50

2

840

13

33.4

2-0.11-5; 4-0.14-3

36.9

3-0.23-6; 4-0.17-3

37.9

2-0.12-3; 3-0.17-6

0.67

0.50

0.33

1

2520

16

65.1

2-0.12-8; 8-0.25-3

65.1

2-0.12-8; 8-0.25-3

67.5

2-0.12-8; 8-0.25-3

1.00

1.00

0.25

2

840

17

57.8

2-0.12-8; 8-0.25-3

57.8

2-0.12-8; 8-0.25-3

60.7

2-0.12-5; 4-0.25-6

1.00

1.00

0.50

2

840

18

54.6

3-0.23-10; 9-0.26-2

54.6

3-0.23-10; 9-0.26-2

56.5

2-0.12-4; 4-0.25-7

1.00

1.00

0.50

2

840

19

49.0

3-0.23-10; 9-0.26-2

51.5

4-0.36-6; 5-0.28-5

52.3

2-0.12-2; 4-0.36-9

0.50

0.50

0.50

2

840

Table 3. Numerical examples with two CREs

Similar to the single-CRE problem with consideration for retailers’ tolerance, we set βi at either 2 or 1.5 for all the retailers of the examples in Table 3. As the results summarized in Table 4 indicate Ex 13, 18 and 19 are the only 3 out of 7 examples affected by the given tolerance limits. Furthermore, the effects are limited on GD0N model for all 3 examples and the effect on EGDRN model occurs only for Ex19. Table 4 indicates that the impact of βi is not only on the number of retailers joining CREs, but also on the choice of the CRE. For example, in CD0N of Ex13 with βi = 1.5, only a single CRE of τ = 3 is selected even though there are two CREs available. The impact of the tolerance limit may reduce the savings; however, the number of retailers joining CREs may increase or decrease. For instance, for EGDRN of Ex19 without retailers’ choices, there are 11 retailers to join CREs, with βi = 2, there are 12 retailers, and with βi = 1.5, there are 10 retailers. The savings of GD0N and EGDRN with or without retailers’ tolerances for Ex19 are all better than the savings of SD. This indicates that GD0N and EGDRN under the restriction of retailers’ choices in this example are able to achieve a better coordination than the SD.




GD0N

EGDRN

Ex

βi

S

(%)

CRE - D(%)-

# Included

S (%)

CRE - D(%)- # Included

φ

φ1

φ2

V

L

13

2.0

36.9

3-0.23-6; 4-0.17-3

37.9

2-0.12-3; 3-0.17-6

0.67

0.50

0.33

1

2520

1.5

26.0

3-0.17-5; 4-0.14-3

37.9

2-0.12-3; 3-0.17-6

0.67

0.50

0.33

1

2520

18

2.0

54.6

3-0.23-10; 9-0.26-2

56.5

2-0.12-4; 4-0.25-7

1.00

1.00

0.50

2

840

1.5

40.3

3-0.20-9

56.5

2-0.12-4; 4-0.25-7

1.00

1.00

0.50

2

840

19

2.0

37.3

4-0.29-4; 5-0.27-5

51.2

2-0.17-4; 4-0.29-8

1.00

1.00

0.50

2

840

1.5

21.8

4-0.44-6; 5-0.28-6

50.2

2-0.12-4; 4-0.25-6

1.00

1.00

0.50

2

840

Table 4. Numerical Examples with two CREs and retailers’ choices

5. Concluding remarks

The contribution of this research is threefold. First, we propose a general MCRE model under the criterion of minimizing the supplier’s total cost without pre-segmenting all or a portion of the retailers into either one of the MCREs or none. Thus, our model can attain better savings than the selective discount model, and reach a better coordination for the supplier. Secondly, our general discount MCRE model further considers retailers’ choices based on the limits of tolerance for the retailers. This mechanism allows the system to prevent any retailer’s cost increase beyond its internal limit. Referring to the objective function in (1) with constraints (2)~(4), our model can be easily modified to deal with the case of no retailers’ choices, by defining the thresholds βi to a very large value such that αij = 1 for all the retailers and CREs. In general, a higher tolerance will reach a higher savings. Third, by defining the unit length of time for all the CREs, our model is able to incorporate additional processing costs Aj for single CRE sets with an exact measurement, and our objective function in (6) extends Piplani and Viswanathan’s model into a general formulation to alleviate order processing costs for entire CRE orders of the supplier. Moreover, if AS can be redefined as disregarding whether a retailer joins the MCRE or not, this case can be accommodated by incorporating all tj with all τj, and then determine joint V and L. Notice that the value of Zjk represent the number of orders placed through a CRE j at time kV. The order processing cost Aj for the CRE j can be further extended from a constant to AS(Zjk) which is a function of the number of orders.

All in all, this research delivers an Exact General Discount (EGD) MCRE model for a supplier to coordinate the ordering and replenishment processes of a set of heterogeneous retailers. The EGD model considers not only the minimization of the supplier’s cost, but also the retailers’ choices as well. The cost minimization in EDG helps the supplier reach a lower cost level than most of the earlier works mentioned previously. The mechanism of incorporating the retailers’ choices in EGD allows the model to have a better fit into the retail industry where suppliers in supply chains may not have exclusive power to control all their retailers. Nevertheless, our model still has certain limitations, such as constant demand rates and instant replenishment lead time. Future research may incorporate variations in demand or/and lead time.

References

7-Eleven, Inc. (2012). Hoover’s Company Records, 41970. Retrieved Septempter 1, 2012 from http://search.proquest.com/docview/230557190?accountid=10534.

Alimentation Couche-Tard, Inc. (2012). Hoover’s Company Records, 104187. Retrieved Septempter 1, 2012 from http://search.proquest.com/docview/230569770?accountid=10534.

Arshinder, Kandaa, A., & Deshmukh, S.G. (2008). Supply chain coordination: perspectives, empirical studies and research directions. International Journal of Production Economics, 115(2), 316-335. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ijpe.2008.05.011

Chan, H.K. (2011). Supply chain Systems- recent trend in research and applications. IEEE System Journal, 5(1), 2-5. http://dx.doi.org/10.1109/JSYST.2010.2100191

Chan, H.K., & Chan, F.T.S. (2010). A review of coordination studies in the context of supply chain dynamics. International Journal of Production Research, 48(10), 2793-2819. http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/00207540902791843

Chen, T., & Chen, J. (2005). Optimizing supply chain collaboration based on joint replenishment and channel coordination. Transportation Research Part E: Logistics and Transportation Review, 41(4), 261-285. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.tre.2004.06.003

FamilyMart Co., Ltd. (2010). Hoover’s Company Records, 55997. Retrieved Septempter 1, 2012 from http://search.proquest.com/docview/230577586?Accountid=10534.

Feng, Y., & Viswanathan, S. (2007). Impact of demand uncertainty on coordinating supply chain inventories through common replenishment epochs. Journal of the Operational Research Society, 58(7), 964-971. http://dx.doi.org/10.1057/palgrave.jors.2602219

Fugate, B., Sahin, F., & Mentzer, T.J. (2006). Supply chain management coordination mechanisms. Journal of Business Logistics, 27(2), 129-161. http://dx.doi.org/10.1002/j.2158-1592.2006.tb00220.x

Goyal, S.K., & Gupta, Y.P. (1989). Integrated inventory models: the buyer vendor co-ordination. European Journal of Operational Research, 41(3), 261-269. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/0377-2217(89)90247-6

Jorgensen, S., & Zaccour, G. (2003). Channel coordination over time: Incentive equilibria and credibility. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 27(5), 801-822. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/S0165-1889(01)00072-0

Li, X., & Wang, Q. (2007). Coordination mechanisms of supply chain systems. European Journal of Operational Research, 179(1), 1-16. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ejor.2006.06.023

Mishra, A.K. (2004). Selective discount for supplier-buyer coordination using common replenishment epochs. European Journal of Operational Research, 153(3), 751-756. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/S0377-2217(02)00811-1

Piplani R., & Viswanathan, S. (2004). Supply chain inventory co-ordination through multiple, common replenishment epochs and selective discount. International Journal of Logistics: Research and Applications, 7(2), 109-118. http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/13675560410001670224

Sarmah, S.P., Acharya, D., & Goyal, S.K. (2006). Buyer vendor coordination models in supply chain management. European Journal of Operational Research, 175(1), 1-15. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ejor.2005.08.006

Sarmah, S.P., Acharya, D., & Goyal, S.K. (2008). Coordination of a single-manufacturer/multi-buyer supply chain with credit option. International Journal of Production Economics, 111(2), 676-685. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ijpe.2007.04.003

Tsay, A.A., Nahmias, S., & Agrawal, N. (1999). Modeling supply chain contracts: a review. In Tayur, S., Ganeshan, R., & Magazine, M. (Eds.). Quantitative models for supply chain management (pp. 299-336). The Netherlands: Kluwer Academic Publishers. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/978-1-4615-4949-9_10

Viswanathan, S., & Piplani, R. (2001). Coordinating supply chain inventories through common replenishment epochs. European Journal of Operational Research, 129(2), 277-286. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/S0377-2217(00)00225-3

Weng, Z.K. (1995). Channel coordination and quantity discounts. Management Science, 41(9), 1509-1523. http://dx.doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.41.9.1509

Wu, S-H., & Hwang, J. (2011). Inventory policies for a supplier facing mixed periodic demand in a single-supplier multi-retailer supply chain. International Journal of Services and Operations Management, 9(1), 32-51. http://dx.doi.org/10.1504/IJSOM.2011.040320

Yao, M., & Chiou, C. (2004). On a replenishment coordination model in an integrated supply chain with one vendor and multiple buyers. European Journal of Operational Research, 159(2), 406-419. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ejor.2003.08.024

Yao, M., & Chiou, C. (2009). A new cooperative scenario for supply chains using common replenishment epochs. Journal of the Operations Research Society of Japan, 52(3), 263-282.





Licencia de Creative Commons 

This work is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License

Journal of Industrial Engineering and Management, 2008-2024

Online ISSN: 2013-0953; Print ISSN: 2013-8423; Online DL: B-28744-2008

Publisher: OmniaScience